The economics of irreparable harm in pharmaceutical patent litigation
CORNERSTONE RESEARCH
FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC CONSULTING AND EXPERT TESTIMONY
The Economics of Irreparable Harm in Pharmaceutical
Patent Litigation
Rahul Guha, Cornerstone ResearchMaria Salgado, Cornerstone Research
TABLE OF CONTENTS
The Hatch-Waxman Act greatly simplifies the process of obtaining FDA approval for a generic drug. Under the Act, a
generic company need only file an Abbreviated New Drug
Application (ANDA) to show that the generic drug is bio-
equivalent to the compound at issue. With bioequivalence
established, the generic company can forgo clinical testing
of its drug for safety and efficacy. Instead, the generic maker
can refer to the clinical data that the branded drug developer
Under the Paragraph IV provision of the Act, a generic company
can attempt to launch a generic drug prior to the expiration of the branded drug's patent(s) either by challenging the validity
of an extant patent on a branded drug or claiming non-infringement of the patent.4 The patent holder then has 45 days
to file a patent infringement suit, which prevents the generic from launching for the next 30 months.5 The 30-month stay holds unless a decision is made in the patent suit or the court orders a different period for the stay. However, if the branded
The Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act
drug company reaches the end of the 30-month stay and the
of 1984,1 also known as the Hatch-Waxman Act, allows generic
patent infringement suit still is not resolved, the generic
products to launch (following U.S. Food and Drug Administra-
company may choose to launch at-risk if it has FDA approval—
tion [FDA] approval) while the patent(s) on the equivalent
that is, before the patent suit is resolved. The first filer(s) of a
branded drug are in litigation. Such a launch is called at-risk
Paragraph IV certification obtains 180 days of exclusivity
because of the possibility that, at trial, the court finds the
during which no other company can launch a generic version
generic drug infringes on the branded drug's patents. Branded
of the branded drug at issue.6
companies often seek a preliminary injunction to prevent the generic from launching at-risk. To obtain such an injunction,
The branded drug company may seek a preliminary injunction
the branded company must establish that it would suffer
to prevent the generic from launching at-risk. To obtain this
irreparable harm due to the generic's at-risk entry—that is, the
injunctive relief, the branded drug company must establish:
harm is irreversible and the branded company cannot be ful y
1. A reasonable likelihood of success on the merits of its
compensated by a monetary damages award if it ultimately pre-
vailed at trial.2 This paper discusses the economic rationale for
2. Irreparable harm if the injunction is not granted;
the different possible sources of irreparable harm that courts
3. That the balance of hardships is on the branded drug; and
consider, such as reductions in research and development
4. That the injunction has a favorable impact on the public
(R&D), loss of share to therapeutic competitors, loss of good-
will, and negative impacts on employment and manufacturing facilities.
The Economics of Irreparable Harm in Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Page 2
When branded drug companies seek preliminary injunctions to
purchasers with the same fixed dollar amount for the branded
prevent at-risk generic entry, the required economic analysis of
drug and its generic equivalent,17 purchasers have a strong
irreparable harm focuses on whether it is possible to quantify
incentive to choose the cheaper generic. And private health-
with precision the impact of a particular generic launch (in
care plans use similar schemes to provide physicians with
which case the branded company could be compensated by a
incentives to reduce drug purchase costs.18
monetary award).8
Of course, the branded drug company could attempt to stem
While in the past companies could rely on a demonstration
losses in prescriptions by reducing the price of its product.19
of success on the merits for a presumption of irreparable
However, even if such a move could avert some losses in the
harm, the Supreme Court's rulings in
eBay v. MercExchange
number of the branded drug's prescriptions, cutting prices
and Winter v. Natural Resources Defense Council challenged the
would most likely reduce revenues. The branded drug com-
presumption of irreparable harm. Further, these cases changed
pany could also attempt to stem losses in prescriptions by
the standard for injunctive relief from showing a "possibility" of
launching a brand-authorized generic. Brand-authorized
irreparable harm to showing a "likelihood" of irreparable harm.
generics, however, allow branded companies to recover only
That has made it even more crucial now to fully understand
some of the lost revenues, for two reasons. First, the brand-
the potential arguments for demonstrating irreparable harm.
authorized generic captures only part of the generic prescrip-tions. For example, approximately 16 months after the launch
DIRECT IMPACT OF GENERIC ENTRY ON BRANDED DRUG
of generic Paxil, the total generic share of prescriptions was
approximately 85 percent, of which the authorized generic
Studies have found that branded drugs lose a majority of their
captured roughly half.20 Second, the price of the brand-
sales to the generic equivalent upon generic entry—over
authorized generic is lower than the price of the branded
75 percent in the first three months and over 80 percent in the
drug. In the first year following the launch of generic Paxil, the
first six months.9 Indeed, the generic share of total prescriptions
authorized generic price was higher than the average inde-
had increased to 74.5 percent by 2009.10 This leads to a loss in
pendent generic price, but after the first year, the prices of the
revenues for the branded drug company upon generic entry.11
authorized generic and independent generics were approxi-mately 50 percent of brand-name Paxil.21
There are many factors that encourage patients to use generic drugs. For example, third party payors (TPPs) such as Medicare
POSSIBLE SOURCES OF IRREPARABLE HARM ARISING FROM
Part D, private insurers, and pharmacy benefit managers
AT-RISK GENERIC ENTRY
(PBMs) charge lower copayments for generic as opposed to branded purchases.12 Pharmacists have strong financial incen-
Reduced revenues for the branded drug overall are amenable
tives to switch patients to the generic because they generally
to reasonably precise quantification. However, several forms of
earn higher margins on the sale of generic drugs than on
harm are difficult to quantify with precision, and courts have
branded versions.13 In most states, this switch may be executed
considered them irreparable. These potential sources of irrepa-
by pharmacists without consulting patients and doctors, unless
rable harm include:
a doctor has indicated in writing on the prescription that it
• Reductions in overall R&D budgets
must be dispensed as written.14 Patients without insurance
• Curtailments in brand-specific R&D and marketing investments
coverage for the drug—as well as patients that face coinsur-
• Loss in share within therapeutic category
ance payments for their drug purchases—have incentives to
• Formulary displacement
purchase generics because they are typically priced at least
• Lost goodwill
25 percent below the branded version of the drug.15 These savings can be seen in the average pharmaceutical treatment
Reductions in Overall R&D Budgets
cost for major therapy areas, which falls by an average of
The dramatic revenue losses for the branded drug manufac-
27.5 percent one year after generic entry, and 35.1 percent
turer typically reduce the company's R&D budget because
two years after generic entry.16
these companies tend to fund R&D with internal financing
Generic drugs that are dispensed by healthcare providers are
sources, such as cash flow and profits, as opposed to external
also encouraged over their branded equivalents. For example,
financing sources, such as equity. As shown by Professor Henry
under Medicare Part B, the purchaser's reimbursement for
Grabowski of Duke University and the late John Vernon, for-
a specialty drug is fixed at the same amount, regardless of
merly a professor at Duke University, internal financing sources
whether a generic or brand is being dispensed. This amount is
are important contributors to pharmaceutical firms' research
106 percent of the volume-weighted average sales price
intensities, which are the ratio of R&D expenditures to sales.22
(ASP) for the drug molecule—that is, the branded drug and its
Professor Vernon has also shown that for every dollar decrease
generic equivalent. Because these policies reimburse
in cash flow, R&D investment decreases by about 22 cents.23
The Economics of Irreparable Harm in Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Page 3
These constraints on R&D funding arise for several reasons,
Branded companies promote their products to physicians and
including the lack of collateral for capital used in R&D and the
patients. In so doing, they provide information to physicians
difficulty of monitoring the firm's behavior due to the uncertain
and patients regarding the drug benefits, and remind physi-
nature of R&D. Borrowers also know more than lenders do
cians and patients about the drug's characteristics.30 Following
about the likelihood that their R&D investments will succeed.
at-risk entry, the branded drug company has a strong incen-
This information asymmetry makes external funding more
tive to reduce promotional expenditures for its product due
costly or not available at all.24 As Professor Bronwyn Hall of the
to these same free-riding issues. Any additional prescriptions
University of California, Berkeley, states, "Investors have more
these promotional efforts generate are likely to be filled by the
difficulty distinguishing good projects from bad when the
cheaper generic drug. However, if the branded company has
projects are long-term R&D investments than when they are
recently obtained FDA approval for use of that drug in a new
more short-term or low-risk projects."25
indication, reduced promotional expenditures can prevent
It is difficult to precisely quantify the impact of forgone R&D
physicians and patients from learning about a potentially help-
on a branded drug company and the patients who could
ful new therapeutic alternative. Economic logic indicates that
have benefitted from the research findings. In large part, this
it is difficult to precisely estimate how physicians and patients
quantification issue arises because the drug development
would have behaved if they had known about the drug's new
process is lengthy, risky, and highly uncertain. In fact, the FDA
indication. Similarly, it is not straightforward to quantify the
estimates that no more than five "in 5,000 tested compounds
benefits that patients would receive if their physicians had
pass… preclinical trials and are proposed for clinical studies."26
prescribed the new treatment option. As a result, the losses to
Moreover, more than three-quarters of all drugs that enter
the branded drug company and its potential patients should
clinical testing ultimately fail to receive marketing approval in
the United States. Even for drugs that receive such marketing approval, the process is lengthy. For the average approved
Loss in Share within Therapeutic Category
drug, the time from the start of clinical testing to marketing
Pharmacies are not allowed to substitute between different
approval is over seven years.27 Consistent with the notion that
branded products unless a physician authorizes it. As a result,
drug development is a highly uncertain process, a number of
competition between branded products differs substantially
drugs that face a significant threat of termination during clini-
from competition between brands and their generic equiva-
cal trials but instead survive later prove to be blockbusters.28
lents. Instead of competing on the prices charged to pharma-
Moreover, it is very difficult to precisely estimate the harm that
cies and wholesalers, therapeutic competition involves con-
cancelation of a research project can have on a branded drug
vincing physicians and patients about the benefits of the drug
company that is in an R&D race. This is because the U.S. patent
through promotions. It also involves competing for business
system provides all rewards associated with an innovation to
from TPPs or their PBMs.31 Promotions by branded companies
the first inventor. As a result, a branded drug company that
provide physicians and patients with information about the
falls behind in an R&D race stands to forgo significant—but
drugs' characteristics.
highly uncertain—profits if it falls behind rivals in researching
Branded drugs typically reduce or eliminate promotional
a drug that subsequently succeeds.29
expenditures upon experiencing generic entry because generic drugs typically benefit from branded promotions. With
Curtailments in Brand-Specific R&D and Marketing
branded promotional expenditures declining on an absolute
basis, the branded drug can suffer a reduction in its share of
Following at-risk generic entry, a branded drug company has
voice within its therapeutic category.32 The lower share of voice
a strong incentive not to pursue R&D that is specific to the
can cause a reduction in the prescriptions for the branded
branded drug at issue. This is because any prescriptions gener-
drug compared to other drugs in its therapeutic category.33
ated by the results of this R&D are likely to be filled by the
Due to this effect, generic entry often causes a decline in the
cheaper generic drug. Because of the generic entrant's ability
total prescriptions for the brand and generic drug combined.
to free ride off the branded drug company's R&D investments,
However, measuring the harm that the branded drug suffers
the branded drug company often delays or curtails R&D efforts
due to its diminished share of voice is inherently difficult; it
specific to that drug. In so doing, however, the branded drug
requires calculating sales that the branded drug loses to each
company forgoes potentially valuable commercial opportuni-
rival drug in a market that is evolving over time. Given the lack
ties associated with the development of new indications for
of precision inherent in such a calculation, these losses may
the drug at issue. In addition, a reduction in drug-specific R&D
also be irreparable.
can bring significant and irreparable harm to patients who could have benefitted from the findings of planned trials for additional indications.
The Economics of Irreparable Harm in Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Page 4
Formulary Displacement
Formulary displacement is another potential cause of
Generic entry can also cause the branded drug at issue to suffer
irreparable harm to branded drug makers whose products
a loss in patient goodwill, even if it prevails in its patent infringe-
are dispensed by pharmacies. Formularies are lists of drugs
ment suit. This is because patients now have to pay more for the
compiled by TPPs, which establish the copayments for pre-
same drug, because the generic is no longer available. These
scription drugs dispensed by pharmacists. Important drivers
losses in patient goodwill and sales are inherently difficult to
of the demand for prescription drugs, formularies often have
quantify, making them another source of irreparable harm aris-
three tiers. Tier 1 is typically reserved for generic drugs, Tier
ing from generic entry. Although loss of goodwill is more diffi-
2 for preferred branded drugs, and Tier 3 for non-preferred
cult to establish than the sources of irreparable harm previously
branded drugs. In tiered formularies, the higher the tier, the
discussed, it can be important in certain circumstances.
higher the copayment is. Thus, generic drugs usually have the
In the case of drugs dispensed by pharmacists, insured
lowest copayments, preferred branded drugs have intermediate
patients are likely to face higher copayments once the generic
copayments, and non-preferred branded drugs have the
is withdrawn. As a result, when the branded drug's generic
highest copayments.34
equivalent is no longer available, patients who had been using
Because of the relatively favorable copayment in Tier 2,
that generic equivalent may switch to using other generics—
branded drug makers seek to maintain this status on formular-
rather than the branded drug—in order to maintain low
ies. However, when a TPP can provide a generic version of the
branded drug at issue on its formulary, the TPP has less reason
In the case of specialty drugs that physicians administer, there
to maintain the branded version on Tier 2. Aware of TPP incen-
is also a significant prospect of lost payor goodwill. This is
tives, the drug's branded competitors often intensify their
because the Medicare Part B reimbursement scheme that
efforts to displace a Tier 2 branded drug when that branded
often applies to such drugs produces reimbursement prices
drug faces generic entry. Rival companies' displacement
that are close to generic levels once the generic has been avail-
efforts typically take the form of offering increased rebates
able to consumers for six to nine months. Thus, if the branded
and product discounts to relevant TPPs. Of course, TPPs may
specialty drug is priced significantly above the Medicare Part
also unilaterally decide to move the branded drug to a higher
B reimbursement price at the time of generic withdrawal,
tier or off the formulary entirely.35
providers who purchase it receive reimbursements that are
When a branded drug loses its Tier 2 status, it is highly uncer-
substantially less than their actual cost. Not surprisingly,
tain whether a subsequent restoration to Tier 2 would happen
physicians (and branded drug companies) would prefer to
in the event of generic withdrawal because the economic con-
avoid this situation, which is referred to as being "under water."
ditions that prevailed when the branded drug was originally
Because losses in patient goodwill are intangible in nature,
placed on Tier 2 may no longer exist by the time the generic
and the switching of former patients from the branded drug to
is withdrawn. For example, new or existing competitors could
generic products is impossible to quantify with precision, both
take over the Tier 2 formulary position, complicating any
effects may be considered irreparable harm to the branded
negotiations to restore the branded drug on Tier 2. Economic
drug company.
analysis therefore suggests that the harm arising from formu-lary displacement should be considered irreparable.36
Other Sources of Irreparable Harm
In the case of physician-administered drugs, if the maker of a
At-risk generic entry can also have other impacts that can
generic withdraws the drug from the market, the reimburse-
irreparably harm the branded drug company, its employees, and
ment amount continues to be based on the volume-weighted
associated educational efforts and patient assistance programs.
ASP of the brand and the generic, due to the two-quarter lag in
First, reductions in the branded drug company's R&D budget, as
reimbursement rates. If, upon generic withdrawal, the price of
well as the abandonment of planned research related to the pat-
the branded drug is at its pre-generic launch level, the reim-
ented drug, could spur an exodus of talent from the company.
bursement amount will likely not cover the cost of the drug.
With the branded drug company having fewer products and
This will either cause the provider to switch to a therapeutic
clinical trials to design and run, many research scientists and
alternative, or cause the branded company to lower the price of
clinicians may seek employment at other companies, including
the brand. In this case, the branded company will only be able
competitors, in order to stay active in their specialty areas. As
to raise the drug price in very small, infrequent increments.
a result, the branded drug company would likely suffer a long-term negative impact. Because that negative impact would be extremely difficult to estimate with precision, economic analysis indicates that it should be irreparable.
The Economics of Irreparable Harm in Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Page 5
The launch of a generic drug could also lead the branded drug
PRIOR COURT DECISIONS ON PRELIMINARY INJUNCTIONS
company to scale back its manufacturing operations and lay
AND THEIR FINDINGS WITH RESPECT TO IRREPARABLE HARM
off employees in manufacturing, packaging, marketing, and
While in the past some courts have held that there should be a
quality control. For example, Wyeth, which faced unexpected
presumption of irreparable harm when the branded drug com-
generic competition for both Protonix and Effexor in late 2007
pany plaintiff has established a reasonable likelihood of success
and early 2008, announced 5,000 potential job cuts in January
on the merits, many also cite the factors discussed above as
2008.38 Similarly, the unexpected launch of a generic version of
additional support for the presumption of irreparable harm.
OxyContin resulted in a loss of more than 1,800 jobs at Purdue
The table below reviews accepted arguments for irreparable
Pharma.39 The negative impact of these layoffs on the branded
harm findings in nine recent cases in which the district courts
drug company itself, as well as its employees, may be difficult
granted preliminary injunctions to branded drug companies.
to quantify with precision and therefore irreparable.
This list is not intended to be exhaustive but merely illustrative
Finally, branded drug companies often budget discretionary
of recent court findings in which plaintiffs have prevailed on
funds to educational grants, patient assistance programs, and
other activities that could be imperiled by at-risk generic entry.
While courts have accepted the aforementioned sources of
Faced with a significant reduction in its revenues, the branded
irreparable harm, this does not occur in every instance. On the
drug company would have strong incentives to cut these and
contrary, whether courts sustain findings of irreparable harm
other discretionary expenditures. Such cuts would have an
depends on the economic and factual issues of the case.
adverse impact on the branded drug company's academic partners, as well as indigent or uninsured patients. Again, it can be very difficult to precisely quantify the impact of these cutbacks on affected parties, creating another source of irrepa-rable harm.
Branded Drug
Case Name
Accepted Arguments for Irreparable Harm
Purdue Pharma v. Roxane, Boehringer Ingelheim
- Lost Research Opportunities
Pharmacia & Upjohn v. Ranbaxy
- Lost Research Opportunities
Warner-Lambert v. Teva
- Lost Right to Exclusion
Sanofi v. Apotex
- Formulary Displacement
- Lost Research Opportunities
- Lost Market Share
Abbott v. Sandoz
Eisai v. Teva
- Lost Research Opportunities
- Formulary Displacement
Eli Lilly v. Teva
- Lost Research Opportunities
- Weakened Relationships with Physicians
- Lost Market Share
King v. Corepharma
- Formulary Displacement
- Maximum Al owable Cost Pricing
- Lost Market Share
Research Foundation of State University of New York v. Mylan
- Lost Research Opportunities
- Weakened Brand Awareness
Table 1.
Prior Court Decisions on Preliminary Injunctions and Their Findings with Respect to Irreparable Harm
The Economics of Irreparable Harm in Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Page 6
10. Ernst R. Berndt and Murray Aitken, "Brand Loyalty, Generic Entry
1. Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984, Pub.
and Price Competition in Pharmaceuticals in the Quarter Century
L. No. 98-417, 98 Stat. 1589 (the "Hatch-Waxman Act" or the "Act").
after the 1984 Waxman-Hatch Legislation" (NBER Working Paper No. 16431, Cambridge, MA, October 2010). The generic share started at
2. According to the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit, "The
18.6 percent in 1984, and rose to 56.4 percent by 2004. The sharp
nature of the patent grant [thus] weighs against holding that mon-
increase from 2004 to 2009 resulted not only from a number of
etary damages will always suffice to make the patentee whole, for
"blockbuster" drugs (such as Pravachol, Zoloft, and Allegra losing
the principal value of a patent is its statutory right to exclude. H.H.
patent protection, but also from the implementation of the 2006
Robertson Co. v. United Steel Deck Inc., 820 F.2d 384, 390 (Fed. Cir.
Medicare Part D benefit.
1987). Similarly, in Hybritech Inc. v. Abbott Laboratories, 849 F.2d 1446, 1451 (Fed. Cir. 1987), the court opined, the "patent statute
11. Although these are not examples of at-risk generic entry, they do
provides injunctive relief to preserve the legal interests of the
illustrate the fact that generic launches cause the pioneer company
parties against future infringement which may have market effects
to lose a significant share of its revenues.
never fully compensable in money."
12.
See, e.g., John Richardson, "PBMs: The Basics and an Industry Over-
3. Due to the ease and limited expense associated with bioequiva-
view," The Health Strategies Consultancy LLC (June 26, 2003), http://
lence testing, the costs associated with filing an ANDA are minimal.
For example, a 2005 study estimates that it typically costs less than
13.
See, e.g., Atanu T. Saha et al., "Generic Competition in the U.S.
$1 million to perform the processing work to get a generic drug
Pharmaceutical Industry,"
International Journal of the Economics of
to a point where it can be approved by the FDA. David Reiffen
Business, 13, no. 1 (February 2006): 15–38.
and Michael R. Ward, "Generic Drug Industry Dynamics,"
Review of
14.
See, e.g., "Survey of Pharmacy Law," National Association of Boards
Economics and Statistics, 87, no. 1 (2005): 37–49. In contrast, the
of Pharmacy (2006).
average U.S. new drug introduction cost over $800 million in 2000,
15.
See, e.g., Atanu T. Saha et al., "Generic Competition in the U.S.
including both pre- and post-approval R&D. Given the fact that
Pharmaceutical Industry,"
International Journal of the Economics
R&D costs historically have been observed to grow faster than the
of Business, 13, no. 1 (February 2006): 15–38. Note that coinsur-
rate of inflation, it is reasonable to expect that current expendi-
ance requires the insured to assume a percentage of the cost of
tures could surpass $1 billion.
See, e.g., Joseph A. DiMasi, Ronald
covered services. In contrast, copayments require the insured to
W. Hansen, and Henry G. Grabowski, "The Price of Innovation: New
pay a flat fee for covered services, for example, $5 per prescription
Estimates of Drug Development Costs,"
Journal of Health Economics,
drug. Unlike coinsurance, it does not vary with the cost of service.
22 (2003): 151–185: Joseph A. DiMasi and Henry G. Grabowski, "The Cost of Biopharmaceutical R&D: Is Biotech Different?"
Managerial
16. Ernst R. Berndt and Murray Aitken, "Brand Loyalty, Generic Entry
and Decision Economics, 28 (2007): 469–479.
and Price Competition in Pharmaceuticals in the Quarter Century after the 1984 Waxman-Hatch Legislation" (NBER Working Paper
4. See "Authorized Generics: An Interim Report," Federal Trade Com-
No. 16431, Cambridge, MA, October 2010). The statistics reflect
mission Report (June 2009): 2, http://
the weighted (by the number of extended units of drugs used)
average across nine major therapeutic classes, which accounted
5. According to the Act, the branded drug company can sue the
for approximately 18 percent of total prescriptions in the United
generic company after 45 days have passed; however, in this situa-
States in 2005.
tion, the automatic 30-month stay does not apply.
17. ASP is defined by the Act as a "manufacturer's sales of a drug to all
6. See "Authorized Generics: An Interim Report," Federal Trade Com-
purchasers in the United States in a calendar quarter divided by
mission Report (June 2009): 2, http://
the total number of units of the drug sold by the manufacturer in
that same quarter. The ASP is net of any price concessions such as
7. See Amazon.com Inc. v. Barnes and Noble.com Inc., 239 F.3d
volume discounts, prompt pay discounts, and cash discounts; free
1343, 1350 (Fed. Cir. 2001). The balance of hardship test focuses
goods contingent on purchase requirements; chargebacks; and
on whether the patent holder will lose more from the claimed
rebates other than those obtained through the Medicaid drug
infringement than an accused infringer will gain. The public inter-
rebate program." See also Daniel R. Levinson, "Monitoring Medi-
est standard focuses on whether there is some critical public inter-
care Part B Drug Prices: A Comparison of Average Sales Price to
est that would be injured by the grant of preliminary relief, given
Average Manufacturer Prices," Department of Health and Human
the public interest in competition.
Services, Office of the Inspector General (April 2006), http://
8. See, e.g., Sanofi-Synthelabo v. Apotex Inc., 488 F.Supp.2d 317
, which notes that the
(S.D.N.Y. 2006); Opinion & Order, Eisai Co. v. Teva Pharmaceuticals
Medicare Part B reimbursement methodology took effect in 2005.
USA, Civ. No. 05-5727 (HAA) (ES) (D.N.J. Mar. 28, 2008).
18.
See, e.g., Patrick Mullen, "The Arrival of Average Sales Price,"
Bio-
9. Henry Grabowski, "Are the Economics of Pharmaceutical Research
technology Healthcare (June 2007): 48–53 at 48, 50. See also
and Development Changing? Productivity, Patents and Political
C. Daniel Mullins et al., "Health Plans' Strategies for Managing Out-
Pressures,"
Pharmacoeconomics, 22, supp. 2 (2004): 15–24. See also
patient Specialty Pharmaceuticals,"
Health Affairs, 25, no. 5 (2006):
John Hudson, "Generic Take-up in the Pharmaceutical Market Fol-
1337; "Commercial Payers Are Starting to Use Medicare's Average
lowing Patent Expiry: A Multi-Country Study," I
nternational Review of
Sales Price,"
Specialty Pharmaceutical News, (March 2006).
Law and Economics, 20 (2000): 205–221; Atanu T. Saha et al., "Generic
19. Here price is defined as net of rebates offered to TPPs.
Competition in the US Pharmaceutical Industry,"
International Jour-
20. Ernst R. Berndt et al., "Authorized Generic Drugs, Price Competi-
nal of the Economics of Business 13, no. 1 (February 2006): 15–38.
tion, and Consumers' Welfare,"
Health Affairs, 26, no. 3 (2007): 790–799.
The Economics of Irreparable Harm in Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Page 7
21. Ibid. However, these two factors may be partially offset by the fact
35. Some formularies may reserve Tier 2 only for branded drugs that
that authorized generic entry may result in a delay in indepen-
do not have generic equivalents. See, e.g., Letter from Federal
dent generic entry, due to generic drug manufacturers not want-
Trade Commission Staff to Virginia Delegate Terry G. Kilgore
ing to compete with other generics.
(October 2, 2006), p. 4, fn. 17, .
22. Henry Grabowski and John A. Vernon, "The Determinants of Phar-
36. Of course, the branded drug company could reduce its price to
maceutical Research and Development Expenditures,"
Journal of
TPPs in order to mitigate this loss of formulary position; such reduc-
Evolutionary Economics, 10 (2000): 201–215.
tions are typically offered in the form of rebates and discounts.
23. John A. Vernon, "Pharmaceutical R&D Investment and Cash Flows:
However, the ability of branded drugs to regain price concessions
An Instrumental Variables Approach to Testing for Capital Market
after the withdrawal of the generic is also unknown and highly
Imperfections,"
Journal of Pharmaceutical Finance, Economics and
uncertain. Thus, the price erosion caused by at-risk generic entry
Policy, 13, no. 4 (2004): 3–17.
could continue after the issuance of an injunction, and the result-ing damages may be difficult to ascertain and thus irreparable
24. Ibid., 13.
37. Academic research has shown that a consumer perceives a loss
25. Bronwyn H. Hall, "The Financing of Research and Development,"
or gain based on the difference between the actual price paid
Oxford Review of Economics Policy, 18, no. 1 (2002): 38.
and his or her reference price, where the reference price could
26. "FDA and the Drug Development Process: How the Agency
reflect the last price paid by the consumer or the consumer's
Ensures That Drugs Are Safe and Effective," Food and Drug Admin-
expectation of the product price. Consumers who reap the gain
istration, Publication No. FS 02-5 (February 2002).
of reduced copayments for a generic could subsequently per-
27. Joseph A. DiMasi, Ronald W. Hansen, and Henry G. Grabowski, "The
ceive a loss with the departure of the generic, due to increased
Price of Innovation: New Estimates of Drug Development Costs,"
copayments. There is a significant academic literature indicat-
Journal of Health Economics, 22, no. 2 (March 2003): 151–185.
ing that consumers assign greater weight to a loss (due to price
28. For example, Mevacor, a Merck product, suffered a "near-fatal set-
increase) than to a gain of the same magnitude.
See, e.g., Daniel
back" in 1980 when clinical trials were cancelled because of safety
D. Kahneman and Amos Tversky, "Prospect Theory: An Analysis
issues that arose in animal trials for a similar compound. After its
of Decision under Risk,"
Econometrica, 47, no. 2 (March 1979):
approval in 1987 by the FDA, however, Mevacor had higher sales
263–92. Hence, the change in copayments discussed above can
than any other prescription medicine in the United States in its
lead to a loss of goodwill.
first 12 months. Mevacor and its successor Zocor are responsible
38. "Wyeth Says It May Cut 10% of Jobs,"
New York Times, January 26,
for billions of dollars in revenue for Merck. "Case 10: Merck(A):
Mevacor," University of Michigan case study,
39. Julie Fishman-Lapin, "A Diversifying Purdue Pharma Hopes to
Regain Control Drug,"
Stamford Advocate, March 4, 2006.
29.
See, e.g., William Robinson et al., "First-Mover Advantages from
Pioneering New Markets: A Survey of Empirical Evidence,"
Review of Industrial Organization, 9 (1994): 5; Ian Cockburn and Rebecca R. Henderson, "Racing to Invest? The Dynamics of Competition in Ethical Drug Discovery,"
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 3, no. 3 (September 1994): 481–519.
30.
See, e.g., Keith B. Leffler, "Persuasion or Information? The Econom-
ics of Prescription Drug Advertising,"
Journal of Law and Econom-ics, 24, no. 1 (1981): 45–74; Ernst R. Berndt et al., "Information, Marketing, and Pricing in the U.S. Antiulcer Drug Market,"
Ameri-can Economic Review, 85, no. 2 (1995): 100–105; Mark A. Hurwitz and Richard E. Caves, "Persuasion or Information? Promotion and the Shares of Brand Name and Generic Pharmaceuticals,"
Journal of Law and Economics, 31, no. 2 (1988): 299–320.
31. PBMs have emerged as the main overseers of the prescription drug
plans of employers and managed care organizations. PBMs have developed various strategies for controlling prescription drug con-sumption. These strategies include formularies, three-tier copay-ment schemes, drug utilization reviews, and rebates from drug manufacturers or suppliers.
32. Because generic drug companies typically do not engage in mar-
keting, this reduction in marketing expenditures will not be offset by additional marketing expenditures from the generic.
33. If new drugs are launched after generic entry, the branded drug
may lose prescriptions to these new drugs as well.
34.
See, e.g., John Richardson, "PBMs: The Basics and an Indus-
try Overview," The Health Strategies Consultancy LLC (June
The views expressed herein are solely those of the authors, who are
26, 2003), 20, http://
responsible for the contents of this report, and do not necessarily represent
the views of Cornerstone Research.
2013 by Cornerstone Research, Inc. All rights reserved.
Source: https://www.cornerstone.com/Publications/Research/The-Economics-of-Irreparable-Harm-in-Pharmaceutical-Patent-Litigation
Köp av bostad i Spanien - en riskfylld affär? Cecilia Nykvist Institutionen för teknik och samhälle Fastighetsvetenskap Lunds Tekniska Högskola Lunds universitet The Departement of Technology and Society Real Estate Science Lund's Institute of Technology Lund University, Sweden Köp av bostad i Spanien – en riskfylld affär?
Quality health plans & benefitsHealthier livingFinancial well-beingIntelligent solutions Discover the benefits of flexible International Healthcare Plan 46.07.310.1-APSL B (9/15) You can count on us to deliver on the goals that matter most to your business and your employees. We share your commitment to caring for your employees and it comes across